HOW CONFIDENT CAN WE BE IN CGE-BASED ASSESSMENTS OF FREE TRADE AGREEMENTS?

With the proliferation of Free Trade Agreements (FTAs) over the past decade, demand for quantitative analysis of their likely impacts has surged. The main quantitative tool for performing such analysis is Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) modeling. Yet these models have been widely criticized for...

Full description

Saved in:
Bibliographic Details
Published inResearch in Agricultural & Applied Economics
Main Authors Hertel, Thomas W, Hummels, David, Ivanic, Maros, Keeney, Roman
Format Paper
LanguageEnglish
Published St. Paul Agricultural & Applied Economics Association (AAEA) 01.01.2003
Edition1237
SeriesGTAP Working Paper No. 26
Subjects
Online AccessGet full text
DOI10.22004/ag.econ.28690

Cover

Abstract With the proliferation of Free Trade Agreements (FTAs) over the past decade, demand for quantitative analysis of their likely impacts has surged. The main quantitative tool for performing such analysis is Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) modeling. Yet these models have been widely criticized for performing poorly (Kehoe, 2002) and having weak econometric foundations (McKitrick, 1998; Jorgenson, 1984). FTA results have been shown to be particularly sensitive to the trade elasticities, with small trade elasticities generating large terms of trade effects and relatively modest efficiency gains, whereas large trade elasticities lead to the opposite result. Critics are understandably wary of results being determined largely by the authors' choice of trade elasticities. Where do these trade elasticities come from? CGE modelers typically draw these elasticities from econometric work that uses time series price variation to identify an elasticity of substitution between domestic goods and composite imports (Alaouze, 1977; Alaouze, et al., 1977; Stern et al., 1976; Gallaway, McDaniel and Rivera, 2003). This approach has three problems: the use of point estimates as "truth", the magnitude of the point estimates, and estimating the relevant elasticity. First, modelers take point estimates drawn from the econometric literature, while ignoring the precision of these estimates. As we will make clear below, the confidence one has in various CGE conclusions depends critically on the size of the confidence interval around parameter estimates. Standard "robustness checks" such as systematically raising or lowering the substitution parameters does not properly address this problem because it ignores information about which parameters we know with some precision and which we do not. A second problem with most existing studies derives from the use of import price series to identify home vs. foreign substitution, for example, tends to systematically understate the true elasticity. This is because these estimates take price variation as exogenous when estimating the import demand functions, and ignore quality variation. When quality is high, import demand and prices will be jointly high. This biases estimated elasticities toward zero. A related point is that the fixed-weight import price series used by most authors are theoretically inappropriate for estimating the elasticities of interest. CGE modelers generally examine a nested utility structure, with domestic production substitution for a CES composite import bundle. The appropriate price series is then the corresponding CES price index among foreign varieties. Constructing such an index requires knowledge of the elasticity of substitution among foreign varieties (see below). By using a fixed-weight import price series, previous estimates place too much weight on high foreign prices, and too small a weight on low foreign prices. In other words, they overstate the degree of price variation that exists, relative to a CES price index. Reconciling small trade volume movements with large import price series movements requires a small elasticity of substitution. This problem, and that of unmeasured quality variation, helps explain why typical estimated elasticities are very small. The third problem with the existing literature is that estimates taken from other researchers' studies typically employ different levels of aggregation, and exploit different sources of price variation, from what policy modelers have in mind. Employment of elasticities in experiments ill-matched to their original estimation can be problematic. For example, estimates may be calculated at a higher or lower level of aggregation than the level of analysis than the modeler wants to examine. Estimating substitutability across sources for paddy rice gives one a quite different answer than estimates that look at agriculture as a whole. When analyzing Free Trade Agreements, the principle policy experiment is a change in relative prices among foreign suppliers caused by lowering tariffs within the FTA. Understanding the substitution this will induce across those suppliers is critical to gauging the FTA's real effects. Using home v. foreign elasticities rather than elasticities of substitution among imports supplied from different countries may be quite misleading. Moreover, these "sourcing" elasticities are critical for constructing composite import price series to appropriate estimate home v. foreign substitutability. In summary, the history of estimating the substitution elasticities governing trade flows in CGE models has been checkered at best. Clearly there is a need for improved econometric estimation of these trade elasticities that is well-integrated into the CGE modeling framework. This paper provides such estimation and integration, and has several significant merits. First, we choose our experiment carefully. Our CGE analysis focuses on the prospective Free Trade Agreement of the Americas (FTAA) currently under negotiation. This is one of the most important FTAs currently "in play" in international negotiations. It also fits nicely with the source data used to estimate the trade elasticities, which is largely based on imports into North and South America. Our assessment is done in a perfectly competitive, comparative static setting in order to emphasize the role of the trade elasticities in determining the conventional gains/losses from such an FTA. This type of model is still widely used by government agencies for the evaluation of such agreements. Extensions to incorporate imperfect competition are straightforward, but involve the introduction of additional parameters (markups, extent of unexploited scale economies) as well as structural assumptions (entry/no-entry, nature of inter-firm rivalry) that introduce further uncertainty. Since our focus is on the effects of a PTA we estimate elasticities of substitution across multiple foreign supply sources. We do not use cross-exporter variation in prices or tariffs alone. Exporter price series exhibit a high degree of multicolinearity, and in any case, would be subject to unmeasured quality variation as described previously. Similarly, tariff variation by itself is typically unhelpful because by their very nature, Most Favored Nation (MFN) tariffs are non-discriminatory in nature, affecting all suppliers in the same way. Tariff preferences, where they exist, are often difficult to measure- sometimes being confounded by quantitative barriers, restrictive rules of origin, and other restrictions. Instead we employ a unique methodology and data set drawing on not only tariffs, but also bilateral transportation costs for goods traded internationally (Hummels, 1999). Transportation costs vary much more widely than do tariffs, allowing much more precise estimation of the trade elasticities that are central to CGE analysis of FTAs. We have highly disaggregated commodity trade flow data, and are therefore able to provide estimates that precisely match the commodity aggregation scheme employed in the subsequent CGE model. We follow the GTAP Version 5.0 aggregation scheme which includes 42 merchandise trade commodities covering food products, natural resources and manufactured goods. With the exception of two primary commodities that are not traded, we are able to estimate trade elasticities for all merchandise commodities that are significantly different form zero at the 95% confidence level. Rather than producing point estimates of the resulting welfare, export and employment effects, we report confidence intervals instead. These are based on repeated solution of the model, drawing from a distribution of trade elasticity estimates constructed based on the econometrically estimated standard errors. There is now a long history of CGE studies based on SSA: Systematic Sensitivity Analysis (Harrison and Vinod, 1992; Wigle, 1991; Pagon and Shannon, 1987) However, to date, all of these studies have taken their parameter distributions "from the literature". None of these studies has been accompanied by an econometric study aimed at estimating the key parameters and their distributions at the relevant level of aggregation used in the CGE analysis. For this paper, we use the Gaussian Quadrature (GQ) approach to SSA, which has proven to be the most efficient and unbiased approach to systematically assessing the sensitivity of model results to parametric uncertainty (DeVuyst and Preckel, 1997; Arndt, 1996). We find that many of the results are qualitatively robust to uncertainty in the trade elasticities. In those cases where our findings are not robust, we explore the source of underlying uncertainty. In this way, the paper addresses the fundamental question: How Robust are CGE Analyses of Free Trade Agreements?
AbstractList With the proliferation of Free Trade Agreements (FTAs) over the past decade, demand for quantitative analysis of their likely impacts has surged. The main quantitative tool for performing such analysis is Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) modeling. Yet these models have been widely criticized for performing poorly (Kehoe, 2002) and having weak econometric foundations (McKitrick, 1998; Jorgenson, 1984). FTA results have been shown to be particularly sensitive to the trade elasticities, with small trade elasticities generating large terms of trade effects and relatively modest efficiency gains, whereas large trade elasticities lead to the opposite result. Critics are understandably wary of results being determined largely by the authors' choice of trade elasticities. Where do these trade elasticities come from? CGE modelers typically draw these elasticities from econometric work that uses time series price variation to identify an elasticity of substitution between domestic goods and composite imports (Alaouze, 1977; Alaouze, et al., 1977; Stern et al., 1976; Gallaway, McDaniel and Rivera, 2003). This approach has three problems: the use of point estimates as "truth", the magnitude of the point estimates, and estimating the relevant elasticity. First, modelers take point estimates drawn from the econometric literature, while ignoring the precision of these estimates. As we will make clear below, the confidence one has in various CGE conclusions depends critically on the size of the confidence interval around parameter estimates. Standard "robustness checks" such as systematically raising or lowering the substitution parameters does not properly address this problem because it ignores information about which parameters we know with some precision and which we do not. A second problem with most existing studies derives from the use of import price series to identify home vs. foreign substitution, for example, tends to systematically understate the true elasticity. This is because these estimates take price variation as exogenous when estimating the import demand functions, and ignore quality variation. When quality is high, import demand and prices will be jointly high. This biases estimated elasticities toward zero. A related point is that the fixed-weight import price series used by most authors are theoretically inappropriate for estimating the elasticities of interest. CGE modelers generally examine a nested utility structure, with domestic production substitution for a CES composite import bundle. The appropriate price series is then the corresponding CES price index among foreign varieties. Constructing such an index requires knowledge of the elasticity of substitution among foreign varieties (see below). By using a fixed-weight import price series, previous estimates place too much weight on high foreign prices, and too small a weight on low foreign prices. In other words, they overstate the degree of price variation that exists, relative to a CES price index. Reconciling small trade volume movements with large import price series movements requires a small elasticity of substitution. This problem, and that of unmeasured quality variation, helps explain why typical estimated elasticities are very small. The third problem with the existing literature is that estimates taken from other researchers' studies typically employ different levels of aggregation, and exploit different sources of price variation, from what policy modelers have in mind. Employment of elasticities in experiments ill-matched to their original estimation can be problematic. For example, estimates may be calculated at a higher or lower level of aggregation than the level of analysis than the modeler wants to examine. Estimating substitutability across sources for paddy rice gives one a quite different answer than estimates that look at agriculture as a whole. When analyzing Free Trade Agreements, the principle policy experiment is a change in relative prices among foreign suppliers caused by lowering tariffs within the FTA. Understanding the substitution this will induce across those suppliers is critical to gauging the FTA's real effects. Using home v. foreign elasticities rather than elasticities of substitution among imports supplied from different countries may be quite misleading. Moreover, these "sourcing" elasticities are critical for constructing composite import price series to appropriate estimate home v. foreign substitutability. In summary, the history of estimating the substitution elasticities governing trade flows in CGE models has been checkered at best. Clearly there is a need for improved econometric estimation of these trade elasticities that is well-integrated into the CGE modeling framework. This paper provides such estimation and integration, and has several significant merits. First, we choose our experiment carefully. Our CGE analysis focuses on the prospective Free Trade Agreement of the Americas (FTAA) currently under negotiation. This is one of the most important FTAs currently "in play" in international negotiations. It also fits nicely with the source data used to estimate the trade elasticities, which is largely based on imports into North and South America. Our assessment is done in a perfectly competitive, comparative static setting in order to emphasize the role of the trade elasticities in determining the conventional gains/losses from such an FTA. This type of model is still widely used by government agencies for the evaluation of such agreements. Extensions to incorporate imperfect competition are straightforward, but involve the introduction of additional parameters (markups, extent of unexploited scale economies) as well as structural assumptions (entry/no-entry, nature of inter-firm rivalry) that introduce further uncertainty. Since our focus is on the effects of a PTA we estimate elasticities of substitution across multiple foreign supply sources. We do not use cross-exporter variation in prices or tariffs alone. Exporter price series exhibit a high degree of multicolinearity, and in any case, would be subject to unmeasured quality variation as described previously. Similarly, tariff variation by itself is typically unhelpful because by their very nature, Most Favored Nation (MFN) tariffs are non-discriminatory in nature, affecting all suppliers in the same way. Tariff preferences, where they exist, are often difficult to measure- sometimes being confounded by quantitative barriers, restrictive rules of origin, and other restrictions. Instead we employ a unique methodology and data set drawing on not only tariffs, but also bilateral transportation costs for goods traded internationally (Hummels, 1999). Transportation costs vary much more widely than do tariffs, allowing much more precise estimation of the trade elasticities that are central to CGE analysis of FTAs. We have highly disaggregated commodity trade flow data, and are therefore able to provide estimates that precisely match the commodity aggregation scheme employed in the subsequent CGE model. We follow the GTAP Version 5.0 aggregation scheme which includes 42 merchandise trade commodities covering food products, natural resources and manufactured goods. With the exception of two primary commodities that are not traded, we are able to estimate trade elasticities for all merchandise commodities that are significantly different form zero at the 95% confidence level. Rather than producing point estimates of the resulting welfare, export and employment effects, we report confidence intervals instead. These are based on repeated solution of the model, drawing from a distribution of trade elasticity estimates constructed based on the econometrically estimated standard errors. There is now a long history of CGE studies based on SSA: Systematic Sensitivity Analysis (Harrison and Vinod, 1992; Wigle, 1991; Pagon and Shannon, 1987) However, to date, all of these studies have taken their parameter distributions "from the literature". None of these studies has been accompanied by an econometric study aimed at estimating the key parameters and their distributions at the relevant level of aggregation used in the CGE analysis. For this paper, we use the Gaussian Quadrature (GQ) approach to SSA, which has proven to be the most efficient and unbiased approach to systematically assessing the sensitivity of model results to parametric uncertainty (DeVuyst and Preckel, 1997; Arndt, 1996). We find that many of the results are qualitatively robust to uncertainty in the trade elasticities. In those cases where our findings are not robust, we explore the source of underlying uncertainty. In this way, the paper addresses the fundamental question: How Robust are CGE Analyses of Free Trade Agreements?
Author Ivanic, Maros
Hertel, Thomas W
Hummels, David
Keeney, Roman
Author_xml – sequence: 1
  givenname: Thomas
  surname: Hertel
  middlename: W
  fullname: Hertel, Thomas W
– sequence: 2
  givenname: David
  surname: Hummels
  fullname: Hummels, David
– sequence: 3
  givenname: Maros
  surname: Ivanic
  fullname: Ivanic, Maros
– sequence: 4
  givenname: Roman
  surname: Keeney
  fullname: Keeney, Roman
BookMark eNotT89PgzAY7UEPOr16buIZLIWV9WQ6KAwzIVlJdmxK93VqFCaT_9_ux-l7yfvxvXePbvqhB4SeIhJSSkjyYvYh2KEP6YJxcofeVs0WZ01dVLmsW5yJGm8lXkpc1TgrZbAUSuZYKCWVevcKhZsCFxspcbsRucSi9PhMvD6gW2e-j_B4vTPUFrLNVsG6KatMrIOD_xgwxjrTWbtzNgJOIObOMAPGzSlYxgEopEnEvTS11DjDI9cxF8VgbeJiSuMZIpfY6afXZn8aowfzeYVHMKP90CcOdpM-r_SW54vlMA6_Exz_9Ncwjb0vqWnK2ILMI0Lif-05VVE
ContentType Paper
Copyright Copyright Agricultural & Applied Economics Association (AAEA) Jan 2003
Copyright_xml – notice: Copyright Agricultural & Applied Economics Association (AAEA) Jan 2003
DBID 3V.
7WY
7WZ
7XB
87Z
8FK
8FL
AAFGM
ABLUL
ABPUF
ABSSA
ABUWG
ACIOU
ADZZV
AFKRA
AGAJT
AGSBL
AJNOY
AQTIP
BENPR
BEZIV
BOUDT
CBHQV
CCPQU
DWQXO
FRNLG
F~G
K60
K6~
L.-
M0C
PHGZM
PHGZT
PKEHL
PQBIZ
PQBZA
PQCXX
PQEST
PQQKQ
PQUKI
PRINS
Q9U
JAG
DOI 10.22004/ag.econ.28690
DatabaseName ProQuest Central (Corporate)
ABI/INFORM Collection
ABI/INFORM Global (PDF only)
ProQuest Central (purchase pre-March 2016)
ABI/INFORM Collection
ProQuest Central (Alumni) (purchase pre-March 2016)
ABI/INFORM Collection (Alumni)
ProQuest Central Korea - hybrid linking
Business Premium Collection - hybrid linking
ABI/INFORM Collection (Alumni) - hybrid linking
ABI/INFORM Collection - hybrid linking
ProQuest Central (Alumni)
ABI/INFORM Global - hybrid linking
ProQuest Central (Alumni) - hybrid linking
ProQuest Central UK/Ireland
ProQuest Central Essentials - hybrid linking
ABI/INFORM Global (Alumni) - hybrid linking
Business Premium Collection (Alumni) - hybrid linking
ProQuest Women's & Gender Studies - hybrid linking
ProQuest Central
Business Premium Collection
ProQuest One Business - hybrid linking
ProQuest One Business (Alumni) - hybrid linking
ProQuest One
ProQuest Central Korea
Business Premium Collection (Alumni)
ABI/INFORM Global (Corporate)
ProQuest Business Collection (Alumni Edition)
ProQuest Business Collection
ABI/INFORM Professional Advanced
ABI/INFORM Global
Proquest Central Premium
ProQuest One Academic (New)
ProQuest One Academic Middle East (New)
ProQuest One Business
ProQuest One Business (Alumni)
ProQuest Central - hybrid linking
ProQuest One Academic Eastern Edition (DO NOT USE)
ProQuest One Academic
ProQuest One Academic UKI Edition
ProQuest Central China
ProQuest Central Basic
AgEcon Search Free
DatabaseTitle ABI/INFORM Global (Corporate)
ProQuest Business Collection (Alumni Edition)
ProQuest One Business
ProQuest One Academic Middle East (New)
ProQuest Central (Alumni Edition)
ProQuest One Community College
ProQuest Central China
ABI/INFORM Complete
ProQuest Central
ABI/INFORM Professional Advanced
ProQuest Central Korea
ProQuest Central (New)
ABI/INFORM Complete (Alumni Edition)
Business Premium Collection
ABI/INFORM Global
ABI/INFORM Global (Alumni Edition)
ProQuest Central Basic
ProQuest One Academic Eastern Edition
ProQuest Business Collection
ProQuest One Academic UKI Edition
ProQuest One Business (Alumni)
ProQuest One Academic
ProQuest Central (Alumni)
Business Premium Collection (Alumni)
ProQuest One Academic (New)
DatabaseTitleList
Database_xml – sequence: 1
  dbid: JAG
  name: AgEcon Search Free
  url: http://ageconsearch.umn.edu/
  sourceTypes: Open Access Repository
– sequence: 2
  dbid: BENPR
  name: ProQuest Central
  url: https://www.proquest.com/central
  sourceTypes: Aggregation Database
DeliveryMethod fulltext_linktorsrc
Edition 1237
ExternalDocumentID oai_ageconsearch_umn_edu_28690
Genre Working Paper/Pre-Print
GroupedDBID 3V.
7WY
7XB
8FK
8FL
ABUWG
AFKRA
AZQEC
BENPR
BEZIV
CCPQU
DWQXO
FRNLG
K60
K6~
L.-
M0C
PHGZM
PHGZT
PKEHL
PQBIZ
PQBZA
PQEST
PQQKQ
PQUKI
PRINS
Q9U
JAG
ID FETCH-LOGICAL-p690-666babccdfc1e90e39fa6aeaf52ec69ee2e74196907c2afa91fb6f13ecc4f3223
IEDL.DBID BENPR
IngestDate Tue Aug 15 23:07:47 EDT 2023
Mon Jun 30 15:16:27 EDT 2025
IsDoiOpenAccess true
IsOpenAccess true
IsPeerReviewed false
IsScholarly false
Language English
LinkModel DirectLink
MergedId FETCHMERGED-LOGICAL-p690-666babccdfc1e90e39fa6aeaf52ec69ee2e74196907c2afa91fb6f13ecc4f3223
Notes SourceType-Working Papers-1
ObjectType-Working Paper/Pre-Print-1
content type line 50
OpenAccessLink https://ageconsearch.umn.edu/record/28690/
PQID 2766805100
PQPubID 6315161
ParticipantIDs umn_agecon_oai_ageconsearch_umn_edu_28690
proquest_journals_2766805100
PublicationCentury 2000
PublicationDate 20030101
2003
PublicationDateYYYYMMDD 2003-01-01
PublicationDate_xml – month: 01
  year: 2003
  text: 20030101
  day: 01
PublicationDecade 2000
PublicationPlace St. Paul
PublicationPlace_xml – name: St. Paul
PublicationSeriesTitle GTAP Working Paper No. 26
PublicationTitle Research in Agricultural & Applied Economics
PublicationYear 2003
Publisher Agricultural & Applied Economics Association (AAEA)
Publisher_xml – name: Agricultural & Applied Economics Association (AAEA)
Score 1.2629834
Snippet With the proliferation of Free Trade Agreements (FTAs) over the past decade, demand for quantitative analysis of their likely impacts has surged. The main...
SourceID umn
proquest
SourceType Open Access Repository
Aggregation Database
SubjectTerms Economic analysis
International Relations/Trade
Trade agreements
SubjectTermsDisplay International Relations/Trade
SummonAdditionalLinks – databaseName: AgEcon Search Free
  dbid: JAG
  link: http://utb.summon.serialssolutions.com/2.0.0/link/0/eLvHCXMwlV07T8MwELZou7CBAFEoyAMLQ2jiJG48obR1-hhS1Aa1W2Q79kaoSvv_OTsFlZHNkh-yv_P5fNb5O4SeKBNJIqXwgioOvUgEoHNxIjyhFCN-FVS6ifLN6fQ9mm_izZEmx_6FASVSNozYSfnwUf_G0uyqPrHZk_ot1LG_LRue_EnDw0isrKHvi3MiXbs_N8YWjHRiNrIL1HkTW727RGe6vkLz6WKNR4s8m415XuBRmuM1x0OOZzkeTbg3TFd8jNOVPeEsxf4KLzKcLTnHxRLwwukEyq7i9RoVGS9GU--YysDbwlw88BGkkEpVRgWa-TpkRlChhYmJVpRpTTRYdmY9VUWEESwwkpogBHwjAyoX3qB2_VnrW4SlgrXHJJF-UkVmIASLlCBJRQJDo4EKu6j3s-7yuB2_SjKgNLHq53fRM2BRNjCXjlv6BPHS1gHipYPw7h9t79G5C3NzjxM91N7vDvoBcN_LRyenb8BBkvo
  priority: 102
  providerName: University of Minnesota
Title HOW CONFIDENT CAN WE BE IN CGE-BASED ASSESSMENTS OF FREE TRADE AGREEMENTS?
URI https://www.proquest.com/docview/2766805100
https://ageconsearch.umn.edu/record/28690/
hasFullText 1
inHoldings 1
isFullTextHit
isPrint
link http://utb.summon.serialssolutions.com/2.0.0/link/0/eLvHCXMwfV07T8MwELagXdhAgCiUygMLg2niPBpPVZo6fQxp1Qa1W2Q7NhNp6eP_Y7upgIXNkiXL_nz3ne98ugPgJSQsijhnyC0DD_nM1ToXRAwxIQh2SreUpyzfLBy_-9N1sK4Dbvs6rfLMiZaoy40wMfIu7oVhZCTI6W-_kOkaZX5X6xYal6CpKTjSct4c0Gy-OFVnxEYCuuzjzbqW2PRe-vOOvDx-Vr-MSXoNmnO2lbsbcCGrWzAdz1YwmWXpZEizHCZxBlcUDiicZDAZUTSIl3QI46XhPVN4fwlnKUwXlMJ8oVGE8UiP7UT_DuQpzZMxqhscoK3eC9KeA2dciFIJVxJHekSxkEmmAixFSKTEUtt7YvxXgZlixFU8VK6nUfeVVkTvHjSqTSUfAOTCJX6AI-5Epa96jBFfMByV2FWh3xNeC7TP5y5qId0XP5C2wKvGotAMppEqbMVpOzxpW2HmtOErLISP_y_1BK5svpuNUrRB47A7ymcN9YF36svpGOoZfQP3opbH
linkProvider ProQuest
linkToHtml http://utb.summon.serialssolutions.com/2.0.0/link/0/eLvHCXMwtV1LTwIxEJ4gHPSmUSOK2oMePKyw3QfbgyE8ujxdCKyB26bbbT0JyCPGH-V_tF0g6sUbtyZNmsx8X2c67XQG4M4lzPPimBlm4liGzUy15xyPGYxzgkuJmYhNlm_gtl7szsSZZOBr9xdGp1XubGJqqJMZ13fkRVx2XU8zqFSZvxu6a5R-Xd210NjQois-P1TItnxqNxS-9xj7NKy3jG1XAWOuIkFDHddjFnOeSG4KUhIWkcxlgkkHC-4SIbBQTpbooJFjJhkxZexK01Ki2lKx31LLHkDO1h9as5Cr0WAw3BSDxJpwRfb6mEayWLd6-nNsPVi_TX_5Lv8YcgM2F4sTyIjpKXRa_TGq9wO_3aBBiOrVAI0pqlHUDlC9SY1adUQbqDrSZlbX-R-hvo_8IaUoHCrQULWpxulE5QzCfUh-DtnpbCouAMXcJLaDvbjkJbYsM0ZszrCXYFO6dplbeSjs5I62e2IZ_SCYhweli0gZTKWpKC1wnQ43KEZ6TvnZKFXh5f9L3cJhK3zuRb120L2CozTVLr0gKUB2tViLa6X2VXyzBQpBtGdqfAPIwtTF
openUrl ctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&ctx_enc=info%3Aofi%2Fenc%3AUTF-8&rfr_id=info%3Asid%2Fsummon.serialssolutions.com&rft_val_fmt=info%3Aofi%2Ffmt%3Akev%3Amtx%3Ajournal&rft.genre=article&rft.atitle=HOW+CONFIDENT+CAN+WE+BE+IN+CGE-BASED+ASSESSMENTS+OF+FREE+TRADE+AGREEMENTS%3F&rft.jtitle=Research+in+Agricultural+%26+Applied+Economics&rft.au=Hertel%2C+Thomas+W&rft.au=Hummels%2C+David&rft.au=Ivanic%2C+Maros&rft.au=Keeney%2C+Roman&rft.date=2003-01-01&rft.pub=Agricultural+%26+Applied+Economics+Association+%28AAEA%29&rft_id=info:doi/10.22004%2Fag.econ.28690