Bayesian probability estimates are not necessary to make choices satisfying Bayes’ rule in elementary situations

This paper has two aims. First, we investigate how often people make choices conforming to Bayes' rule when natural sampling is applied. Second, we show that using Bayes' rule is not necessary to make choices satisfying Bayes' rule. Simpler methods, even fallacious heuristics, might p...

Full description

Saved in:
Bibliographic Details
Published inFrontiers in psychology Vol. 6; p. 1194
Main Authors Domurat, Artur, Kowalczuk, Olga, Idzikowska, Katarzyna, Borzymowska, Zuzanna, Nowak-Przygodzka, Marta
Format Journal Article
LanguageEnglish
Published Switzerland Frontiers Media S.A 17.08.2015
Subjects
Online AccessGet full text
ISSN1664-1078
1664-1078
DOI10.3389/fpsyg.2015.01194

Cover

Abstract This paper has two aims. First, we investigate how often people make choices conforming to Bayes' rule when natural sampling is applied. Second, we show that using Bayes' rule is not necessary to make choices satisfying Bayes' rule. Simpler methods, even fallacious heuristics, might prescribe correct choices reasonably often under specific circumstances. We considered elementary situations with binary sets of hypotheses and data. We adopted an ecological approach and prepared two-stage computer tasks resembling natural sampling. Probabilistic relations were inferred from a set of pictures, followed by a choice which was made to maximize the chance of a preferred outcome. Use of Bayes' rule was deduced indirectly from choices. Study 1 used a stratified sample of N = 60 participants equally distributed with regard to gender and type of education (humanities vs. pure sciences). Choices satisfying Bayes' rule were dominant. To investigate ways of making choices more directly, we replicated Study 1, adding a task with a verbal report. In Study 2 (N = 76) choices conforming to Bayes' rule dominated again. However, the verbal reports revealed use of a new, non-inverse rule, which always renders correct choices, but is easier than Bayes' rule to apply. It does not require inversion of conditions [transforming P(H) and P(D|H) into P(H|D)] when computing chances. Study 3 examined the efficiency of three fallacious heuristics (pre-Bayesian, representativeness, and evidence-only) in producing choices concordant with Bayes' rule. Computer-simulated scenarios revealed that the heuristics produced correct choices reasonably often under specific base rates and likelihood ratios. Summing up we conclude that natural sampling results in most choices conforming to Bayes' rule. However, people tend to replace Bayes' rule with simpler methods, and even use of fallacious heuristics may be satisfactorily efficient.
AbstractList This paper has two aims. First, we investigate how often people make choices conforming to Bayes' rule when natural sampling is applied. Second, we show that using Bayes' rule is not necessary to make choices satisfying Bayes' rule. Simpler methods, even fallacious heuristics, might prescribe correct choices reasonably often under specific circumstances. We considered elementary situations with binary sets of hypotheses and data. We adopted an ecological approach and prepared two-stage computer tasks resembling natural sampling. Probabilistic relations were inferred from a set of pictures, followed by a choice which was made to maximize the chance of a preferred outcome. Use of Bayes' rule was deduced indirectly from choices. Study 1 used a stratified sample of N = 60 participants equally distributed with regard to gender and type of education (humanities vs. pure sciences). Choices satisfying Bayes' rule were dominant. To investigate ways of making choices more directly, we replicated Study 1, adding a task with a verbal report. In Study 2 (N = 76) choices conforming to Bayes' rule dominated again. However, the verbal reports revealed use of a new, non-inverse rule, which always renders correct choices, but is easier than Bayes' rule to apply. It does not require inversion of conditions [transforming P(H) and P(D|H) into P(H|D)] when computing chances. Study 3 examined the efficiency of three fallacious heuristics (pre-Bayesian, representativeness, and evidence-only) in producing choices concordant with Bayes' rule. Computer-simulated scenarios revealed that the heuristics produced correct choices reasonably often under specific base rates and likelihood ratios. Summing up we conclude that natural sampling results in most choices conforming to Bayes' rule. However, people tend to replace Bayes' rule with simpler methods, and even use of fallacious heuristics may be satisfactorily efficient.This paper has two aims. First, we investigate how often people make choices conforming to Bayes' rule when natural sampling is applied. Second, we show that using Bayes' rule is not necessary to make choices satisfying Bayes' rule. Simpler methods, even fallacious heuristics, might prescribe correct choices reasonably often under specific circumstances. We considered elementary situations with binary sets of hypotheses and data. We adopted an ecological approach and prepared two-stage computer tasks resembling natural sampling. Probabilistic relations were inferred from a set of pictures, followed by a choice which was made to maximize the chance of a preferred outcome. Use of Bayes' rule was deduced indirectly from choices. Study 1 used a stratified sample of N = 60 participants equally distributed with regard to gender and type of education (humanities vs. pure sciences). Choices satisfying Bayes' rule were dominant. To investigate ways of making choices more directly, we replicated Study 1, adding a task with a verbal report. In Study 2 (N = 76) choices conforming to Bayes' rule dominated again. However, the verbal reports revealed use of a new, non-inverse rule, which always renders correct choices, but is easier than Bayes' rule to apply. It does not require inversion of conditions [transforming P(H) and P(D|H) into P(H|D)] when computing chances. Study 3 examined the efficiency of three fallacious heuristics (pre-Bayesian, representativeness, and evidence-only) in producing choices concordant with Bayes' rule. Computer-simulated scenarios revealed that the heuristics produced correct choices reasonably often under specific base rates and likelihood ratios. Summing up we conclude that natural sampling results in most choices conforming to Bayes' rule. However, people tend to replace Bayes' rule with simpler methods, and even use of fallacious heuristics may be satisfactorily efficient.
This paper has two aims. First, we investigate how often people make choices conforming to Bayes’ rule when natural sampling is applied. Second, we show that using Bayes’ rule is not necessary to make choices satisfying Bayes’ rule. Simpler methods, even fallacious heuristics, might prescribe correct choices reasonably often under specific circumstances. We considered elementary situations with binary sets of hypotheses and data. We adopted an ecological approach and prepared two-stage computer tasks resembling natural sampling. Probabilistic relations were inferred from a set of pictures, followed by a choice which was made to maximize the chance of a preferred outcome. Use of Bayes’ rule was deduced indirectly from choices. Study 1 used a stratified sample of N = 60 participants equally distributed with regard to gender and type of education (humanities vs. pure sciences). Choices satisfying Bayes’ rule were dominant. To investigate ways of making choices more directly, we replicated Study 1, adding a task with a verbal report. In Study 2 ( N = 76) choices conforming to Bayes’ rule dominated again. However, the verbal reports revealed use of a new, non-inverse rule, which always renders correct choices, but is easier than Bayes’ rule to apply. It does not require inversion of conditions [transforming P(H) and P(D|H) into P(H|D)] when computing chances. Study 3 examined the efficiency of three fallacious heuristics (pre-Bayesian, representativeness, and evidence-only) in producing choices concordant with Bayes’ rule. Computer-simulated scenarios revealed that the heuristics produced correct choices reasonably often under specific base rates and likelihood ratios. Summing up we conclude that natural sampling results in most choices conforming to Bayes’ rule. However, people tend to replace Bayes’ rule with simpler methods, and even use of fallacious heuristics may be satisfactorily efficient.
This paper has two aims. First, we investigate how often people make choices conforming to Bayes’ rule when natural sampling is applied. Second, we show that using Bayes’ rule is not necessary to make choices satisfying Bayes’ rule. Simpler methods, even fallacious heuristics, might prescribe correct choices reasonably often under specific circumstances. We considered elementary situations with binary sets of hypotheses and data. We adopted an ecological approach and prepared two-stage computer tasks resembling natural sampling. Probabilistic relations were to be inferred from a set of pictures, followed by a choice between the data which was made to maximize a chance for a preferred outcome. Using Bayes’ rule was deduced indirectly from choices.Study 1 (N=60) followed a 2 (gender: female vs. male) x 2 (education: humanities vs. pure sciences) between-subjects factorial design with balanced cells, and a number of correct choices as a dependent variable. Choices satisfying Bayes’ rule were dominant. To investigate ways of making choices more directly, we replicated Study 1, adding a task with a verbal report. In Study 2 (N=76) choices conforming to Bayes’ rule dominated again. However, the verbal reports revealed use of a new, non-inverse rule, which always renders correct choices, but is easier than Bayes’ rule to apply. It does not require inversing conditions (transforming P(H) and P(D|H) into P(H|D)) when computing chances). Study 3 examined efficiency of the three fallacious heuristics (pre-Bayesian, representativeness, and evidence-only) in producing choices concordant with Bayes’ rule. Computer-simulated scenarios revealed that the heuristics produce correct choices reasonably often under specific base rates and likelihood ratios. Summing up we conclude that natural sampling leads to most choices conforming to Bayes’ rule. However, people tend to replace Bayes’ rule with simpler methods, and even use of fallacious heuristics may be satisfactorily efficient.
This paper has two aims. First, we investigate how often people make choices conforming to Bayes' rule when natural sampling is applied. Second, we show that using Bayes' rule is not necessary to make choices satisfying Bayes' rule. Simpler methods, even fallacious heuristics, might prescribe correct choices reasonably often under specific circumstances. We considered elementary situations with binary sets of hypotheses and data. We adopted an ecological approach and prepared two-stage computer tasks resembling natural sampling. Probabilistic relations were inferred from a set of pictures, followed by a choice which was made to maximize the chance of a preferred outcome. Use of Bayes' rule was deduced indirectly from choices. Study 1 used a stratified sample of N = 60 participants equally distributed with regard to gender and type of education (humanities vs. pure sciences). Choices satisfying Bayes' rule were dominant. To investigate ways of making choices more directly, we replicated Study 1, adding a task with a verbal report. In Study 2 (N = 76) choices conforming to Bayes' rule dominated again. However, the verbal reports revealed use of a new, non-inverse rule, which always renders correct choices, but is easier than Bayes' rule to apply. It does not require inversion of conditions [transforming P(H) and P(D|H) into P(H|D)] when computing chances. Study 3 examined the efficiency of three fallacious heuristics (pre-Bayesian, representativeness, and evidence-only) in producing choices concordant with Bayes' rule. Computer-simulated scenarios revealed that the heuristics produced correct choices reasonably often under specific base rates and likelihood ratios. Summing up we conclude that natural sampling results in most choices conforming to Bayes' rule. However, people tend to replace Bayes' rule with simpler methods, and even use of fallacious heuristics may be satisfactorily efficient.
Author Borzymowska, Zuzanna
Idzikowska, Katarzyna
Kowalczuk, Olga
Nowak-Przygodzka, Marta
Domurat, Artur
AuthorAffiliation 4 Laboratory of Visual System, Nencki Institute of Experimental Biology Warsaw, Poland
3 Centre for Economic Psychology and Decision Sciences, Kozminski University Warsaw, Poland
1 Department of Cognitive Psychology, Faculty of Psychology, University of Warsaw Warsaw, Poland
2 Center for Complex Systems and New Technologies, The Robert B. Zajonc Institute for Social Studies, University of Warsaw Warsaw, Poland
AuthorAffiliation_xml – name: 4 Laboratory of Visual System, Nencki Institute of Experimental Biology Warsaw, Poland
– name: 2 Center for Complex Systems and New Technologies, The Robert B. Zajonc Institute for Social Studies, University of Warsaw Warsaw, Poland
– name: 3 Centre for Economic Psychology and Decision Sciences, Kozminski University Warsaw, Poland
– name: 1 Department of Cognitive Psychology, Faculty of Psychology, University of Warsaw Warsaw, Poland
Author_xml – sequence: 1
  givenname: Artur
  surname: Domurat
  fullname: Domurat, Artur
– sequence: 2
  givenname: Olga
  surname: Kowalczuk
  fullname: Kowalczuk, Olga
– sequence: 3
  givenname: Katarzyna
  surname: Idzikowska
  fullname: Idzikowska, Katarzyna
– sequence: 4
  givenname: Zuzanna
  surname: Borzymowska
  fullname: Borzymowska, Zuzanna
– sequence: 5
  givenname: Marta
  surname: Nowak-Przygodzka
  fullname: Nowak-Przygodzka, Marta
BackLink https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pubmed/26347676$$D View this record in MEDLINE/PubMed
BookMark eNp1Ustu1DAUjVARLaV7VshLNjPYjmPHGySoKFSqxAbW1o3nZuqS2IPtVMqO3-D3-JJ6MqVqkfDG1vU5577Oy-rIB49V9ZrRdV23-l2_S_N2zSlr1pQxLZ5VJ0xKsWJUtUeP3sfVWUo3tBxBOaX8RXXMZS2UVPKkih9hxuTAk10MHXRucHkmmLIbIWMiEJH4kIlHiylBnEkOZIQfSOx1cCVGEmSX-tn5LVm0_vz6TeI0IHGe4IAj-rynJZenggw-vaqe9zAkPLu_T6vvF5--nX9ZXX39fHn-4WplheR51bWy7uuWKyGUQkY1MA2CbRAkdppR2_XYcAZUo4JGtFY1taAbygRXveh1fVpdHnQ3AW7MLpaO4mwCOLMEQtwaiNnZAQ2ztgNZhoU9FR1l0KCVilutNeuQYdF6f9DaTd2IG1uaijA8EX3649212YZbI5rSgqBF4O29QAw_pzJfM7pkcRjAY5iSYYpR2dRcqAJ98zjXQ5K_SysAegDYGFKK2D9AGDV7a5jFGmZvDbNYo1DkPxTr8rKOUq0b_k-8A_LIwm4
CitedBy_id crossref_primary_10_3758_s13423_022_02075_3
crossref_primary_10_1002_ajp_23565
crossref_primary_10_1016_j_actpsy_2017_04_003
crossref_primary_10_3389_fpsyg_2020_00863
crossref_primary_10_3389_fpsyg_2015_01872
Cites_doi 10.1016/0010-0277(95)00664-8
10.1086/428020
10.3389/fpsyg.2015.00340
10.1111/j.0956-7976.2004.00715.x
10.1002/bdm.681
10.3389/fpsyg.2014.01144
10.1111/j.1539-6924.2006.00847.x
10.1026//1618-3169.50.2.97
10.2307/1884852
10.1111/j.1745-6916.2008.00058.x
10.1017/CBO9780511840265
10.1080/00223980.1988.9915525
10.1037/h0034747
10.1007/s00199-012-0692-4
10.1037/h0042769
10.3758/BF03195278
10.1037/xge0000013
10.3758/s13423-013-0464-6
10.1017/CBO9780511809477.011
10.1007/978-94-010-2288-0-3
10.1037/0096-3445.130.3.380
10.1007/978-1-4612-4308-3-27
10.1080/14792779143000033
10.1037/e683322011-032
10.1002/9780470752937.ch1
10.3389/fpsyg.2015.00387
10.1017/S1930297500005775
10.1037/0033-295X.87.3.215
10.1037/0096-3445.127.1.3
10.1002/jhbs.21579
10.1017/S0140525X00041157
10.1080/09540129850124451
10.1016/S0001-6918(96)00028-5
10.3389/fpsyg.2014.01272
10.1017/S1930297500001315
10.1037/h0060889
10.3389/fpsyg.2015.00642
10.1037/0033-2909.130.6.959
10.1016/S0749-5978(03)00021-9
10.1017/CBO9780511809477.019
10.1017/S0140525X07001653
10.1002/9780470752937.ch4
10.1002/acp.1460
10.1016/j.cognition.2004.12.003
10.1016/S0010-0277(00)00133-5
10.1037/0033-295X.84.3.231
10.1016/j.tics.2009.09.004
10.1037/0033-295X.102.4.684
10.1037/h0023653
10.1037/0033-295x.106.2.417
ContentType Journal Article
Copyright Copyright © 2015 Domurat, Kowalczuk, Idzikowska, Borzymowska and Nowak-Przygodzka. 2015 Domurat, Kowalczuk, Idzikowska, Borzymowska and Nowak-Przygodzka
Copyright_xml – notice: Copyright © 2015 Domurat, Kowalczuk, Idzikowska, Borzymowska and Nowak-Przygodzka. 2015 Domurat, Kowalczuk, Idzikowska, Borzymowska and Nowak-Przygodzka
DBID AAYXX
CITATION
NPM
7X8
5PM
DOA
DOI 10.3389/fpsyg.2015.01194
DatabaseName CrossRef
PubMed
MEDLINE - Academic
PubMed Central (Full Participant titles)
DOAJ Directory of Open Access Journals
DatabaseTitle CrossRef
PubMed
MEDLINE - Academic
DatabaseTitleList MEDLINE - Academic


PubMed
Database_xml – sequence: 1
  dbid: DOA
  name: DOAJ Directory of Open Access Journals
  url: https://www.doaj.org/
  sourceTypes: Open Website
– sequence: 2
  dbid: NPM
  name: PubMed
  url: https://proxy.k.utb.cz/login?url=http://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/entrez/query.fcgi?db=PubMed
  sourceTypes: Index Database
DeliveryMethod fulltext_linktorsrc
Discipline Psychology
EISSN 1664-1078
ExternalDocumentID oai_doaj_org_article_1ccba6107ef04b01a5ec672c9991be1e
PMC4538240
26347676
10_3389_fpsyg_2015_01194
Genre Journal Article
GroupedDBID 53G
5VS
9T4
AAFWJ
AAKDD
AAYXX
ABIVO
ACGFO
ACGFS
ACHQT
ACXDI
ADBBV
ADRAZ
AEGXH
AFPKN
AIAGR
ALMA_UNASSIGNED_HOLDINGS
AOIJS
BAWUL
BCNDV
CITATION
DIK
EBS
EJD
EMOBN
F5P
GROUPED_DOAJ
GX1
HYE
IPNFZ
KQ8
M48
M~E
O5R
O5S
OK1
P2P
PGMZT
RIG
RNS
RPM
NPM
7X8
5PM
ID FETCH-LOGICAL-c462t-b863f38274477e109a19a41dea6eb910cbfe521a09e7a548c75340d01427f4f93
IEDL.DBID M48
ISSN 1664-1078
IngestDate Wed Aug 27 01:04:08 EDT 2025
Thu Aug 21 13:48:52 EDT 2025
Fri Sep 05 05:06:44 EDT 2025
Mon Jul 21 05:50:47 EDT 2025
Tue Jul 01 01:45:05 EDT 2025
Thu Apr 24 23:02:55 EDT 2025
IsDoiOpenAccess true
IsOpenAccess true
IsPeerReviewed true
IsScholarly true
Keywords Bayes’ rule
natural sampling
heuristics
ecological rationality
binary hypothesis
non-inverse rule
choices
Language English
License This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY). The use, distribution or reproduction in other forums is permitted, provided the original author(s) or licensor are credited and that the original publication in this journal is cited, in accordance with accepted academic practice. No use, distribution or reproduction is permitted which does not comply with these terms.
LinkModel DirectLink
MergedId FETCHMERGED-LOGICAL-c462t-b863f38274477e109a19a41dea6eb910cbfe521a09e7a548c75340d01427f4f93
Notes ObjectType-Article-1
SourceType-Scholarly Journals-1
ObjectType-Feature-2
content type line 23
This article was submitted to Cognition, a section of the journal Frontiers in Psychology
Edited by: Gorka Navarrete, Universidad Diego Portales, Chile
Reviewed by: Gaëlle Vallée-Tourangeau, Kingston University London, UK; David E. Over, Durham University, UK
OpenAccessLink http://journals.scholarsportal.info/openUrl.xqy?doi=10.3389/fpsyg.2015.01194
PMID 26347676
PQID 1710653247
PQPubID 23479
ParticipantIDs doaj_primary_oai_doaj_org_article_1ccba6107ef04b01a5ec672c9991be1e
pubmedcentral_primary_oai_pubmedcentral_nih_gov_4538240
proquest_miscellaneous_1710653247
pubmed_primary_26347676
crossref_primary_10_3389_fpsyg_2015_01194
crossref_citationtrail_10_3389_fpsyg_2015_01194
ProviderPackageCode CITATION
AAYXX
PublicationCentury 2000
PublicationDate 2015-08-17
PublicationDateYYYYMMDD 2015-08-17
PublicationDate_xml – month: 08
  year: 2015
  text: 2015-08-17
  day: 17
PublicationDecade 2010
PublicationPlace Switzerland
PublicationPlace_xml – name: Switzerland
PublicationTitle Frontiers in psychology
PublicationTitleAlternate Front Psychol
PublicationYear 2015
Publisher Frontiers Media S.A
Publisher_xml – name: Frontiers Media S.A
References Yamagishi (B54) 2003; 50
Gigerenzer (B19) 1995; 102
Gigerenzer (B15) 1991; 2
Brase (B7) 2015; 6
Cosmides (B10) 1996; 58
Camilleri (B9) 2009; 4
Simon (B47) 1955; 69
Gigerenzer (B20) 1998; 10
Nance (B38) 2005; 34
Sirota (B49) 2014; 21
Villejoubert (B53) 2002; 30
Tyszka (B52) 2006; 26
Karni (B31) 2013; 53
Edwards (B13) 1968
Navarrete (B39) 2014; 5
Mandel (B35) 2014; 5
Tversky (B51) 1982
Brase (B5) 2008; 23
Barbey (B3) 2007; 30
Huber (B28) 1997; 95
Pleskac (B43) 2014; 143
Kleiter (B33) 1994
Brase (B6) 1998; 127
Hertwig (B24) 2004; 15
Kahneman (B30) 1973; 80
Mellers (B37) 1999; 106
Simon (B48) 1956; 63
Sloman (B50) 2003; 91
Dhami (B11) 2004; 130
Ayal (B2) 2014; 9
Ericsson (B14) 1980; 87
Hertwig (B25) 2009; 13
Eddy (B12) 1982
Koehler (B34) 1996; 19
Girotto (B23) 2001; 78
Brunswik (B8) 1943; 50
Over (B41) 2004
Phillips (B42) 1966; 72
Hoffrage (B27) 2015; 6
Gigerenzer (B17) 2004
Gigerenzer (B16) 1998
Hertwig (B26) 2001; 24
Baron (B4) 1994
Karp (B32) 1988; 122
Gigerenzer (B18) 2008; 3
Anderson (B1) 2000
Zhu (B55) 2006; 98
Mandel (B36) 2015; 6
Giocoli (B22) 2013; 49
Kahneman (B29) 1972; 3
Rakow (B44) 2010; 14
Savage (B45) 1954
Gigerenzer (B21) 1999
Nisbett (B40) 1977; 84
Sedlmeier (B46) 2001; 130
25414688 - Front Psychol. 2014 Nov 06;5:1272
16399266 - Cognition. 2006 Jan;98(3):287-308
23794254 - Psychon Bull Rev. 2014 Feb;21(1):198-204
5968681 - J Exp Psychol. 1966 Sep;72(3):346-54
15535744 - Psychol Bull. 2004 Nov;130(6):959-88
13310708 - Psychol Rev. 1956 Mar;63(2):129-38
19836292 - Trends Cogn Sci. 2009 Dec;13(12):517-23
3172033 - J Psychol. 1988 Jul;122(4):383-8
11561916 - J Exp Psychol Gen. 2001 Sep;130(3):380-400
12693194 - Exp Psychol. 2003;50(2):97-106
12035879 - Mem Cognit. 2002 Mar;30(2):171-8
17963533 - Behav Brain Sci. 2007 Jun;30(3):241-54; discussion 255-97
25873904 - Front Psychol. 2015 Mar 31;6:340
11124351 - Cognition. 2001 Mar;78(3):247-76
9625903 - AIDS Care. 1998 Apr;10(2):197-211
11682798 - Behav Brain Sci. 2001 Jun;24(3):383-403; discussion 403-51
24979239 - J Exp Psychol Gen. 2014 Oct;143(5):2000-19
17184402 - Risk Anal. 2006 Dec;26(6):1623-36
25346713 - Front Psychol. 2014 Oct 09;5:1144
25904882 - Front Psychol. 2015 Apr 08;6:387
26157397 - Front Psychol. 2015 Jun 22;6:642
23165740 - J Hist Behav Sci. 2013 Winter;49(1):63-95
26158666 - Perspect Psychol Sci. 2008 Jan;3(1):20-9
15270998 - Psychol Sci. 2004 Aug;15(8):534-9
References_xml – volume: 58
  start-page: 1
  year: 1996
  ident: B10
  article-title: Are humans good intuitive statisticians after all? Rethinking some conclusions from the literature on judgment under uncertainty.
  publication-title: Cognition
  doi: 10.1016/0010-0277(95)00664-8
– volume: 34
  start-page: 395
  year: 2005
  ident: B38
  article-title: Juror understanding of DNA evidence: an empirical assessment of presentation formats for trace evidence with a relatively small random-match probability.
  publication-title: J. Legal Stud.
  doi: 10.1086/428020
– volume: 6
  issue: 340
  year: 2015
  ident: B7
  article-title: Good fences make for good neighbors but bad science: a review of what improves Bayesian reasoning and why.
  publication-title: Front. Psychol.
  doi: 10.3389/fpsyg.2015.00340
– volume: 15
  start-page: 534
  year: 2004
  ident: B24
  article-title: Decisions from experience and the effect of rare events in risky choice.
  publication-title: Psychol. Sci.
  doi: 10.1111/j.0956-7976.2004.00715.x
– volume: 14
  start-page: 1
  year: 2010
  ident: B44
  article-title: Degrees of uncertainty: an overview and framework for future research on experience-based choice.
  publication-title: J. Behav. Decis. Mak.
  doi: 10.1002/bdm.681
– volume: 5
  issue: 1144
  year: 2014
  ident: B35
  article-title: The psychology of Bayesian reasoning.
  publication-title: Front. Psychol.
  doi: 10.3389/fpsyg.2014.01144
– volume: 26
  start-page: 1623
  year: 2006
  ident: B52
  article-title: When does information about probability count in choices under risk?
  publication-title: Risk Anal.
  doi: 10.1111/j.1539-6924.2006.00847.x
– volume: 50
  start-page: 97
  year: 2003
  ident: B54
  article-title: Facilitating normative judgments of conditional probability: frequency or nested sets?
  publication-title: Exp. Psychol.
  doi: 10.1026//1618-3169.50.2.97
– year: 1954
  ident: B45
  publication-title: The Foundations of Statistics.
– volume: 69
  start-page: 99
  year: 1955
  ident: B47
  article-title: A behavioral model of rational choice.
  publication-title: Q. J. Econ.
  doi: 10.2307/1884852
– volume: 3
  start-page: 20
  year: 2008
  ident: B18
  article-title: Why heuristics work.
  publication-title: Perspect. Psychol. Sci.
  doi: 10.1111/j.1745-6916.2008.00058.x
– year: 1994
  ident: B4
  publication-title: Thinking and Deciding
  doi: 10.1017/CBO9780511840265
– year: 1999
  ident: B21
  publication-title: Simple Heuristics that Make Us Smart.
– volume: 122
  start-page: 383
  year: 1988
  ident: B32
  article-title: Color associations of male and female fourth-grade school children.
  publication-title: J. Psychol.
  doi: 10.1080/00223980.1988.9915525
– volume: 80
  start-page: 237
  year: 1973
  ident: B30
  article-title: On the psychology of prediction.
  publication-title: Psychol. Rev.
  doi: 10.1037/h0034747
– volume: 53
  start-page: 335
  year: 2013
  ident: B31
  article-title: Bayesian decision theory with action-dependent probabilities and risk attitudes.
  publication-title: Econ. Theory
  doi: 10.1007/s00199-012-0692-4
– volume: 63
  start-page: 129
  year: 1956
  ident: B48
  article-title: Rational choice and the structure of environment.
  publication-title: Psychol. Rev.
  doi: 10.1037/h0042769
– volume: 30
  start-page: 171
  year: 2002
  ident: B53
  article-title: The inverse fallacy: an account of deviations from Bayes theorem and the additivity principle.
  publication-title: Mem. Cogn.
  doi: 10.3758/BF03195278
– volume: 143
  start-page: 2000
  year: 2014
  ident: B43
  article-title: Ecologically rational choice and the structure of the environment.
  publication-title: J. Exp. Psychol.
  doi: 10.1037/xge0000013
– volume: 21
  start-page: 198
  year: 2014
  ident: B49
  article-title: Ecological rationality or nested sets? Individual differences in cognitive processing predict Bayesian reasoning.
  publication-title: Psychon. Bull. Rev.
  doi: 10.3758/s13423-013-0464-6
– start-page: 153
  year: 1982
  ident: B51
  article-title: “Evidential impact of base rates,” in
  publication-title: Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases
  doi: 10.1017/CBO9780511809477.011
– volume: 3
  start-page: 430
  year: 1972
  ident: B29
  article-title: Subjective probability: a judgment of representativeness.
  publication-title: Cogn. Psychol.
  doi: 10.1007/978-94-010-2288-0-3
– volume: 130
  start-page: 380
  year: 2001
  ident: B46
  article-title: Teaching Bayesian reasoning in less than two hours.
  publication-title: J. Exp. Psychol.
  doi: 10.1037/0096-3445.130.3.380
– start-page: 375
  year: 1994
  ident: B33
  article-title: “Natural sampling: rationality without base rates,” in
  publication-title: Contributions to Mathematical Psychology, Psychometrics, and Methodology
  doi: 10.1007/978-1-4612-4308-3-27
– volume: 2
  start-page: 83
  year: 1991
  ident: B15
  article-title: How to make cognitive illusions disappear: beyond heuristics and biases.
  publication-title: Eur. Rev. Soc. Psychol.
  doi: 10.1080/14792779143000033
– volume: 24
  start-page: 383
  year: 2001
  ident: B26
  article-title: Experimental practices in economics: a methodological challenge for psychologists?
  publication-title: Behav. Brain Sci.
  doi: 10.1037/e683322011-032
– start-page: 3
  year: 2004
  ident: B41
  article-title: “Rationality and the normative/descriptive distinction,” in
  publication-title: Blackwell Handbook of Judgment and Decision Making
  doi: 10.1002/9780470752937.ch1
– volume: 6
  issue: 387
  year: 2015
  ident: B36
  article-title: Instruction in information structuring improves Bayesian judgment in intelligence analysts.
  publication-title: Front. Psychol.
  doi: 10.3389/fpsyg.2015.00387
– volume: 9
  start-page: 226
  year: 2014
  ident: B2
  article-title: The effects of mental steps and compatibility on Bayesian reasoning.
  publication-title: Judgm. Decis. Mak.
  doi: 10.1017/S1930297500005775
– volume: 87
  start-page: 215
  year: 1980
  ident: B14
  article-title: Verbal reports as data.
  publication-title: Psychol. Rev.
  doi: 10.1037/0033-295X.87.3.215
– volume: 127
  start-page: 3
  year: 1998
  ident: B6
  article-title: Individuation, counting, and statistical inference: the role of frequency and whole-object representations in judgment under uncertainty.
  publication-title: J. Exp. Psychol. Gen.
  doi: 10.1037/0096-3445.127.1.3
– volume: 49
  start-page: 63
  year: 2013
  ident: B22
  article-title: From wald to savage: homo economicus becomes a Bayesian statistician.
  publication-title: J. Hist. Behav. Sci.
  doi: 10.1002/jhbs.21579
– start-page: 9
  year: 1998
  ident: B16
  article-title: “Ecological intelligence. An adaptation for frequencies,” in
  publication-title: The Evolution of Mind
– volume: 19
  start-page: 1
  year: 1996
  ident: B34
  article-title: The base rate fallacy reconsidered: descriptive, normative, and methodological challenges.
  publication-title: Behav. Brain Sci.
  doi: 10.1017/S0140525X00041157
– volume: 10
  start-page: 197
  year: 1998
  ident: B20
  article-title: AIDS counseling for low-risk clients.
  publication-title: AIDS Care
  doi: 10.1080/09540129850124451
– volume: 95
  start-page: 15
  year: 1997
  ident: B28
  article-title: Active information search and complete information presentation in naturalistic risky decision tasks.
  publication-title: Acta Psychol.
  doi: 10.1016/S0001-6918(96)00028-5
– volume: 5
  issue: 1272
  year: 2014
  ident: B39
  article-title: Communicating risk in prenatal screening: the consequences of Bayesian misapprehension.
  publication-title: Front. Psychol.
  doi: 10.3389/fpsyg.2014.01272
– volume: 4
  start-page: 518
  year: 2009
  ident: B9
  article-title: The role of representation in experience-based choice.
  publication-title: Judgm. Decis. Mak.
  doi: 10.1017/S1930297500001315
– volume: 50
  start-page: 255
  year: 1943
  ident: B8
  article-title: Organismic achievement and environmental probability.
  publication-title: Psychol. Rev.
  doi: 10.1037/h0060889
– volume: 6
  issue: 642
  year: 2015
  ident: B27
  article-title: Natural frequencies facilitate diagnostic inferences of managers.
  publication-title: Front. Psychol.
  doi: 10.3389/fpsyg.2015.00642
– volume: 130
  start-page: 959
  year: 2004
  ident: B11
  article-title: The role of representative design in an ecological approach to cognition.
  publication-title: Psychol. Bull.
  doi: 10.1037/0033-2909.130.6.959
– volume: 91
  start-page: 296
  year: 2003
  ident: B50
  article-title: Frequency illusions and other fallacies.
  publication-title: Organ. Behav. Hum. Decis. Process.
  doi: 10.1016/S0749-5978(03)00021-9
– start-page: 249
  year: 1982
  ident: B12
  article-title: “Probabilistic reasoning in clinical medicine: problems and opportunities,” in
  publication-title: Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases
  doi: 10.1017/CBO9780511809477.019
– year: 2000
  ident: B1
  publication-title: Learning and Memory: An Integrated Approach
– volume: 30
  start-page: 241
  year: 2007
  ident: B3
  article-title: Base-rate respect: from ecological rationality to dual processes.
  publication-title: Behav. Brain Sci.
  doi: 10.1017/S0140525X07001653
– start-page: 62
  year: 2004
  ident: B17
  article-title: “Fast and frugal heuristics: the tools of bounded rationality,” in
  publication-title: Blackwell Handbook of Judgment and Decision Making
  doi: 10.1002/9780470752937.ch4
– volume: 23
  start-page: 369
  year: 2008
  ident: B5
  article-title: Pictorial representations in statistical reasoning.
  publication-title: Appl. Cogn. Psychol.
  doi: 10.1002/acp.1460
– volume: 98
  start-page: 287
  year: 2006
  ident: B55
  article-title: Children can solve Bayesian problems: the role of representation in mental computation.
  publication-title: Cognition
  doi: 10.1016/j.cognition.2004.12.003
– volume: 78
  start-page: 247
  year: 2001
  ident: B23
  article-title: Solving probabilistic and statistical problems: a matter of information structure and question form.
  publication-title: Cognition
  doi: 10.1016/S0010-0277(00)00133-5
– start-page: 17
  year: 1968
  ident: B13
  article-title: “Conservatism in human information processing,” in
  publication-title: Formal Representation of Human Judgment
– volume: 84
  start-page: 231
  year: 1977
  ident: B40
  article-title: Telling more than we can know: verbal reports on mental processes.
  publication-title: Psychol. Rev.
  doi: 10.1037/0033-295X.84.3.231
– volume: 13
  start-page: 517
  year: 2009
  ident: B25
  article-title: The description–experience gap in risky choice.
  publication-title: Trends Cogn. Sci.
  doi: 10.1016/j.tics.2009.09.004
– volume: 102
  start-page: 684
  year: 1995
  ident: B19
  article-title: How to improve Bayesian reasoning without instruction: frequency formats.
  publication-title: Psychol. Rev.
  doi: 10.1037/0033-295X.102.4.684
– volume: 72
  start-page: 346
  year: 1966
  ident: B42
  article-title: Conservatism in a simple probability inference task.
  publication-title: J. Exp. Psychol.
  doi: 10.1037/h0023653
– volume: 106
  start-page: 417
  year: 1999
  ident: B37
  article-title: How to improve Bayesian reasoning: comment on Gigerenzer and Hoffrage (1995).
  publication-title: Psychol. Rev.
  doi: 10.1037/0033-295x.106.2.417
– reference: 24979239 - J Exp Psychol Gen. 2014 Oct;143(5):2000-19
– reference: 12693194 - Exp Psychol. 2003;50(2):97-106
– reference: 9625903 - AIDS Care. 1998 Apr;10(2):197-211
– reference: 13310708 - Psychol Rev. 1956 Mar;63(2):129-38
– reference: 17963533 - Behav Brain Sci. 2007 Jun;30(3):241-54; discussion 255-97
– reference: 12035879 - Mem Cognit. 2002 Mar;30(2):171-8
– reference: 25346713 - Front Psychol. 2014 Oct 09;5:1144
– reference: 3172033 - J Psychol. 1988 Jul;122(4):383-8
– reference: 19836292 - Trends Cogn Sci. 2009 Dec;13(12):517-23
– reference: 25904882 - Front Psychol. 2015 Apr 08;6:387
– reference: 11561916 - J Exp Psychol Gen. 2001 Sep;130(3):380-400
– reference: 23794254 - Psychon Bull Rev. 2014 Feb;21(1):198-204
– reference: 11124351 - Cognition. 2001 Mar;78(3):247-76
– reference: 23165740 - J Hist Behav Sci. 2013 Winter;49(1):63-95
– reference: 15270998 - Psychol Sci. 2004 Aug;15(8):534-9
– reference: 16399266 - Cognition. 2006 Jan;98(3):287-308
– reference: 25414688 - Front Psychol. 2014 Nov 06;5:1272
– reference: 26157397 - Front Psychol. 2015 Jun 22;6:642
– reference: 15535744 - Psychol Bull. 2004 Nov;130(6):959-88
– reference: 11682798 - Behav Brain Sci. 2001 Jun;24(3):383-403; discussion 403-51
– reference: 25873904 - Front Psychol. 2015 Mar 31;6:340
– reference: 17184402 - Risk Anal. 2006 Dec;26(6):1623-36
– reference: 5968681 - J Exp Psychol. 1966 Sep;72(3):346-54
– reference: 26158666 - Perspect Psychol Sci. 2008 Jan;3(1):20-9
SSID ssj0000402002
Score 2.1178184
Snippet This paper has two aims. First, we investigate how often people make choices conforming to Bayes' rule when natural sampling is applied. Second, we show that...
This paper has two aims. First, we investigate how often people make choices conforming to Bayes’ rule when natural sampling is applied. Second, we show that...
SourceID doaj
pubmedcentral
proquest
pubmed
crossref
SourceType Open Website
Open Access Repository
Aggregation Database
Index Database
Enrichment Source
StartPage 1194
SubjectTerms Bayesian inference
Bayes’ rule
Binary hypothesis
choices
ecological rationality
Heuristics
Psychology
SummonAdditionalLinks – databaseName: DOAJ Directory of Open Access Journals
  dbid: DOA
  link: http://utb.summon.serialssolutions.com/2.0.0/link/0/eLvHCXMwrV3NbtQwELaqnnpB5a-EAjJSLz1Eaydee3OkiKpCghOVerNsZ0xXtNkqyR5y62v09XgSZpx0tYsQXLgmtmN57Jlv4plvGDsRoRRF5VReq4XIVSx97jVIVIYQyqKWwRnKRv7yVV9cqs9X86utUl8UEzbSA48LN5MheIc23kAUygvp5hC0KQIBGw8SSPuKSmw5U0kHk1tEoTt0L4leWDWLd93wnUK5iKZTVmrHDiW6_j9hzN9DJbdsz_khezKBRv5hnOxTtgfNM3aw0V3Dc9aeuQEoH5JThZiRe3vgxKBxS2CSuxZ4s-p5A5QW4NqB9yt-634AxyFIV_AupTlQ0hNPY_28f-Dt-gb4suEwxZhjt27Zj-Tg3Qt2ef7p28eLfCqnkAeliz73C13GckGUgMaAFJWTKCRZg9PgETUEHwGNuRMVGIeOTEBPRokafajCRBWr8iXbb1YNvGJc1qVyCoTGTlRM3ckihIid4iJKEPOMzR4X14aJa5xKXtxY9DlIHDaJw5I4bBJHxk43Pe5Gno2_tD0jeW3aEUN2eoD7xk77xv5r32Ts_aO0LZ4ouiZxDazWnZUIuvQcgabJ2NEo_c2nCl0qo43OmNnZFztz2X3TLK8Ta7dC04Lw6fX_mPwxO6DloH_b0rxh-327hrcIjnr_Lp2DXxLyEn0
  priority: 102
  providerName: Directory of Open Access Journals
Title Bayesian probability estimates are not necessary to make choices satisfying Bayes’ rule in elementary situations
URI https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pubmed/26347676
https://www.proquest.com/docview/1710653247
https://pubmed.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/PMC4538240
https://doaj.org/article/1ccba6107ef04b01a5ec672c9991be1e
Volume 6
hasFullText 1
inHoldings 1
isFullTextHit
isPrint
link http://utb.summon.serialssolutions.com/2.0.0/link/0/eLvHCXMwfV1Nb9QwELWgXHpB5TstrYyEhDiE2onXzh5QRRFVhVROrNRb5DjjsmKbLElWav49M0526aKFaxI7H2PPvOd43jD2VrhUJFOr4lJlIlY-LeJCg0RnCC5NSumsoWzkq2_6cqa-Xk-u_6RHjx-w3UntqJ7UrFl8uPvVn-GE_0iME-PtqV-2_Q3t0iIFTiTlD9kjjEuaqNjVCPaDXyaqNGxC1Fqh_zHZ8N9yZyekEqxTZTSpkdwLWUHZfxcc_XtX5b0wdXHAHo_4kn8aBsQT9gCqp2x_4-b6Z2x5bnug1ElOxWQGme6ek9jGLeFObhvgVd3xCiiDwDY972p-a38Cxy7IrfA2ZERQfhQPfb3jzWoBfF5xGDejY6N23g0q4u1zNrv48v3zZTzWXYid0kkXF5lOfZqRdqAxIMXUSrSmLMFqKBBeuMIDRn0rpmAsMh6HlEeJEslWYrzy0_QF26vqCl4xLstUWQVCYyOqum5l4pzHRj7zEsQkYqfrT5u7UZScamMsciQnZJc82CUnu-TBLhF7v2mxHAQ5_nPtOVlrcx1JaYcDdXOTjzMzl84VFkGkAS9UIaSdgNMmcYScC5AQsTdrW-c49eh_iq2gXrW5RHSmJ4hITcReDrbf3Go9diJmtkbF1rNsn6nmP4K8t8IYhDjr8J99HrF9ekda2ZbmNdvrmhUcIzTqipOwpHASxv1vnP8N3g
linkProvider Scholars Portal
openUrl ctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&ctx_enc=info%3Aofi%2Fenc%3AUTF-8&rfr_id=info%3Asid%2Fsummon.serialssolutions.com&rft_val_fmt=info%3Aofi%2Ffmt%3Akev%3Amtx%3Ajournal&rft.genre=article&rft.atitle=Bayesian+probability+estimates+are+not+necessary+to+make+choices+satisfying+Bayes%27+rule+in+elementary+situations&rft.jtitle=Frontiers+in+psychology&rft.au=Domurat%2C+Artur&rft.au=Kowalczuk%2C+Olga&rft.au=Idzikowska%2C+Katarzyna&rft.au=Borzymowska%2C+Zuzanna&rft.date=2015-08-17&rft.issn=1664-1078&rft.eissn=1664-1078&rft.volume=6&rft.spage=1194&rft_id=info:doi/10.3389%2Ffpsyg.2015.01194&rft_id=info%3Apmid%2F26347676&rft.externalDocID=26347676
thumbnail_l http://covers-cdn.summon.serialssolutions.com/index.aspx?isbn=/lc.gif&issn=1664-1078&client=summon
thumbnail_m http://covers-cdn.summon.serialssolutions.com/index.aspx?isbn=/mc.gif&issn=1664-1078&client=summon
thumbnail_s http://covers-cdn.summon.serialssolutions.com/index.aspx?isbn=/sc.gif&issn=1664-1078&client=summon